Home | Contact | Links | ||
|
Theme: The Economic Solution for the Period of Transition from Capitalism to CommunismThe Basic Theoretical Foundations of the Work “Fundamental Principles of Communist Production and Distribution”Supplement to “Fundamental Principles of Communist Production and Distribution” published by Neue Arbeiterverlag, Berlin 1931 from Dutch. Source: Fundamental Principles of Communist Production and Distribution / Collective Work of the Group of International Communists of Holland (g.i.k.) ; [On the cover: by Jan Appel]. – London&bnbsp;: Movement for Workers’ Councils, 1990. – xii, 589 p. The translation by Mike Baker is “edited” in the sense that he sometimes tries to “ameliorate” and “complete” the work of the g.i.c.; instead of “Basic Principles” he translates “Basic Theoretical Foundations”; he also sometimes translates “Workers’ Councils” by “Works Councils” which was corrected here; and he added comments in notes (16 pages) which can be consulted in the pdf of the whole book; here re-edited somewhat more according to the German original, notably for the titles, but without full revision. I. The Basic Theoretical Foundations of the Work “Fundamental Principles of Communist Production and Distribution”a. The Workers’ Councils as Organisational FoundationIn our Work “Fundamental Principles of Communist Production and Distribution”, the establishment of a Communist society is viewed from a quite different aspect from that which has previously been customary in the working class movement. To a certain degree it was the course of development taken by the Russian Revolution which was the causal premise placing firmly on the agenda the necessity to carry through a closer examination of the problems of Communist economic life. It is only necessary to read the Russian “Factory Decrees” to recognise that the workers there have no influence whatever upon the course of economic life, which inevitably leads to the conclusion that the right of disposal over the productive apparatus lies in the hands of subjectively motivated administrators and managers, and that the workers under Russian state communism have remained wage workers. In addition, one would have to be blind not to see that the profit motive is the foundation of Russian production, just as everywhere else in the capitalist world; that production is not organised to ensure the satisfaction of the needs of the producers. A further reason compelling us to make a closer examination of this matter lies in the new situation which has arisen in respect of agrarian production. In our work: “Perspectives of Development in Agriculture” we have shown that agrarian production is now completely socialised – that the peasant economy has now been transformed completely into “industrial production”, but that the agrarian question nevertheless remains the great barrier which would render impossible any attempt to implement those forms of “socialism” or “communism” which reflect the conventionally prevalent conception of those societies. Agricultural production is organically unamenable to integration into the “communist economy”, – i.e., into the state administration. From this we draw the conclusion that the entire conception of this form of “communism” must be false. The third and perhaps the weightiest reason making it necessary to carry out an examination of the problems of Communist production lay in the fact that the working class during the period of the revolution needed other forms of organisation than those which were prevalent in the working class movement during the period of peaceful “improvement of working conditions”. The organisational structure of the revolutionary workers’ movement then finds its definitive form in the Factory Organisations and Workers’ Councils. However, there exists a close association between the organisational structure of a movement and the various idea-systems through which that movement expresses itself in terms of consciously motivated social practice. This interconnection is so profound that it is possible to define the various organisational structures as functional instruments serving the idea-systems through which the working class movement is defined in conscious terms. The organisational structures adopted by the various tendencies within the proletarian movement then develop along parallel courses alongside the differing idea-systems through which the particular modes of construction of the Communist society then prevalent are conceptually expressed. If at the same time we also perceive the emergence of structural changes in the practice of class struggle, this may be taken as a sure indication that important changes in the sphere of the various idea-systems have taken place which, even at that very moment, are seeking in this way to find their appropriate organisational expression. In revolutionary periods important changes in the realm of ideas take place which develop with an otherwise unknown rapidity. The motivation underlying the workers’ struggles is completely transformed and becomes fully radicalised. One of the most important lessons to be learned from the revolutionary period 1917-1923 is that the idea-concepts which then underwent transformation acquired a totally different organisational expression from those adopted by the old workers’ movement. The most violent struggle then comes to be enjoined against that old movement, extending even to bloody conflicts, and all for the reason that these older organisations have opposed themselves to the new aims adopted by the now radicalised workers and their new movements, which in their turn reflect the newly-formed systems of ideas. The Factory Organisations and Workers’ Councils are the organisational weapons by means of which the workers carry through the revolution. The importance that was ascribed to the concept of Workers’ Councils at the beginning of the revolutionary period is revealed in, for instance, a survey prepared by D.J. Struik on the occasion of the Resolution on the Workers’ Councils adopted at that time by the Communist Party of Holland. We read there: “Nothing reveals more clearly the progress we have achieved in our understanding of the laws of the social revolution than does our Declaration concerning the Council system. A mere two years ago, this declaration would have been quite impossible; and if we return to just three years ago, even the clearest minds then at work in the International would have had virtually nothing to say about the significance of the Councils in the form in which we now see them.” It will be a difficult task to find opinions expressive of this kind of spirit anywhere in the pre-war literature... Up to the time of the February revolution of 1917 statements were everywhere restricted to a simple declaration of the changes which were considered necessary in the political and economic forms through which the revolution was expected to express itself. Any more exact indication than this was, so far as we know, not attempted, at least not on this side of the Weichsel. In the whole of her pamphlet on the mass strike Rosa Luxemburg writes only once in passing concerning the Council of Workers’ Delegates of 1905. In his book on the First Russian Revolution Trotsky writes at length concerning the history, the significance and the power of this first Workers’ Council, but he does not concern himself in any similar depth with an examination of the Council System as such. And even in the Marxist publications which appeared during the first half of the World War, in for instance “Der Vorbote” (“The Harbinger”), “Der Lichtstrahl” (“Ray of Light”), etc.,·any reference whatever to the Petrograd Soviet of 1905 is wholly absent. The fact that, a short while after the outbreak of the February Revolution of 1917, the Soviet concept began to acquire such a firm foothold and widespread acceptance is exclusively the outcome of the revolutionary praxis underlying the revolution itself... If ever the well-known dictum of Mehring: “Die Intuition der handelnden Massen genialer sein kann denn das grösste Genie” (“The intuition of the masses in action can have more of genius in it than the work of the greatest individual genius”) has received confirmation, then it has been in this case. The highest and most positive quality that the revolutionary period of 1917-1923 has given us consists in the fact that it has enabled us to see the forms which the proletarian revolution must assume in order to complete itself, whilst at the same time it has brought to light the world view which is the expression of the new forms of class struggle in the sphere of ideas. The seizure of control over the social apparatus of production is carried out by the Factory Organisations and, most definitively, by the organs brought into being through their combination, the Workers’ Councils. For this reason, any examination of the problems associated with Communist production and distribution must proceed on the foundation of these new organs of proletarian power and the idea-world which has arisen on that foundation: “The Workers’ Councils will one day become the essence b. The Marxist Definition of the Fundamental Social Preconditions determining the Domination of the Working ClassIn addition to the role of the factory organisations, we have as the second point of commencement for the fundamental principles of the communist economic system the Marxist definition of the social preconditions underlying the domination and exploitation of the working class. We are concerned here in the first instance not with repeating as many quotations from Marx as possible, but with the clearest possible elucidation of the general line of thought, the essential theoretical foundations of his analysis. The foundations upon which the domination and exploitation of the working class take place are in their essentials extremely simple and immediately comprehensible to everybody: they are comprised in the simple fact that the workers are separated from control over the means of production. The capitalist is the owner of the means of production – the workers possess only their labour power: the capitalist holds in his possession the conditions under which the workers must labour. This places the workers in an economic situation in which they are without any rights or power whatsoever, and this is so even if political democracy has been developed to the highest point of perfection. They are totally dependent upon capital. Along with its right of control over the means of production, the owning class has simultaneously the right of disposal over labour-power; that is to say, it dominates and rules over the working class. Expressed as succinctly as possible, this means that: THE RIGHT OF DISPOSAL OVER THE MEANS OF PRODUCTION EXERCISED BY THE RULING CLASS PLACES THE WORKING CLASS IN A RELATIONSHIP OF DEPENDENCE UPON CAPITAL. This is the most essential. The fact that the working class is separated from control of the means of production includes within itself the fact that they also have no control over the finished product of their labour. The workers have no connection whatever with the articles their labour has produced; they do not belong to them but to their “master”. What takes place after that is not their concern; their role is solely to sell their labour-power and then to exert it on behalf of the capitalist, and to receive in exchange their wages:they are WAGE WORKERS. Given the essentials of the situation, this could not be otherwise. Control over the productive apparatus includes the right of disposal over the finished product. They are merely two different sides of the same relationship they are functionally interdependent, the one cannot exist without the other, the one can exist only through the other. Because the workers do not have any right of control over the productive apparatus, for that reason they also have no right of disposal over the finished product; this is the fundamental means through which the form of domination over the workers is exercised, it is fundamentally from this cause that they are forced to become wage workers. Wage-labour is the expression of the fact that labour is separated from the product of labour, that the workers have no rights either over the products of their labour or over the productive apparatus. The existence of wage-labour is the certain sign of the absence of any responsibility on the part of the working class for or over the production process, a certain sign that they are ruled over by those who do hold the right of disposal over the social apparatus of product;on and the social product. However simple the foundations of the system of rule over the working class may be, the foundations for the elimination of wage-slavery are just as simple – even if their practical implementation is by no means so easy. The abolition of wage-slavery can only be achieved when the division between labour and the product of labour has been overcome; when the right of disposal over the product of labour, and therefore also over the means of product ion, has come into the hands of the workers themselves. That is the most essential of Communist production. It is no longer possible, of course, that this can happen in the same simple way as once the craft worker obtained his rights over his tools and the product of his labour. Present day society knows nothing of individual, self-sufficient labour; it has long since gone over to social production, to a fully socialised labour process, in which each individual is only a tiny cog in a gigantic machine. It is for this reason that the workers today must hold possession of the means of production socially. Social ownership, however, which does not simultaneously include the right of control over production, has failed in its purpose. Socialised forms of control are not an end in themselves, but only the means for realising this right of control over the means of production for the workers – a means of eliminating the separation of labour from the product of labour, a means of enabling the abolition of wage-labour to be accomplished. c. The Confusion of Aims with MeansIt is here that we discover the weak spot in the present day labour movement. The aim is proclaimed of bringing the means of production into common ownership, and it apparently occurs to no one that this cannot in fact be any aim at all; no one even suspects the fact that, with the transformation of society into “common ownership”, the problem of how a new mode of production comes to be established is first posed. The working class lives under the false illusion that Communism will somehow happen “of itself”, simply as a result of the elimination of private property in the means of production. But the assumption that wage-labour must necessarily disappear when this is achieved is false. The real strategic aim of proletarian power can only be the conquering by the workers of the right of control over the means of production, and therewith also over the product of their labour. By this means, they simultaneously eliminate the entire basis for wage-labour. Only by this means does the working class become “free”. The socially exercised right of disposal over production by the free producers – that is the foundation of Communist society. However, having once won control over the means of production, the free producers cannot dispose of those means arbitrarily, just as they wish, as do the “free proprietors” under capitalism, the factory owners or “captains of industry”. So soon as that power of disposal becomes arbitrary, a socially exercised right of control becomes impossible. The first precondition for ensuring that the right of disposal over the productive apparatus is socially implemented resides in ensuring that production is carried out according to generally valid principles, principles upon which all social labour must be founded. Only then are decisions and actions possible which are socially arrived at. To achieve this, the free producers must create equal conditions of production for all producers. So soon as this is achieved, production rests on the same foundation throughout the whole of society. The free producers therewith simultaneously become "equal producers". In this way the industrial organisations in their combinations of the most varied kind come to embody “The Association of Free and Equal Producers”. Seen from this viewpoint, the demand for equality is seen to arise, not in any way from any “ethical” or “moral” foundation, but far rather to have been born out of the necessary conditions of production peculiar to Communist economic life itself. Here “equality” is seen to be no ethical concept, but an economic one. It seeks to give expression to nothing other than that production in all the industrial organisations proceeds according to the same laws, in order that a social right of disposal over the productive apparatus may be made possible. The securing of these laws for the whole of production as a binding obligation: that is the essential task of a proletarian revolution. Thus we see that the moral demand for equality, which is a central demand we place upon Communism and which is simultaneously the precondition for the full unfolding of individuality, has its foundation in equality of production. The Social-Democratic Revision of Marxism
|
January 1919: | Introduction of free postal deliveries; |
February 1919: | Decree concerning transport of goods between state factories without any bank transfer and without any record of account; |
June 1919: | Introduction of free transport of goods on the railways. |
The “nationalisation of wages” was introduced in stages throughout the entire period from 1918 to 1921. At the end of this period, only 15% of wages were paid out in money form, whilst 85% were paid in kind. Telephone charges, gas, water supply, electricity, rents, fuel and transport were all supplied free of charge. The Commissariat for Food Supplies had as its responsibility the provisioning of 58 million citizens by this means.
Thus the regulation and accounting of production and distribution needs would not take place through the form bf money, or in any other general measure, but only in totals or quantities of goods supplied. Account would be kept according to weight, length or area, or finally only according to the piece-number of consumption goods supplied. In a word, the intention was to move over to a “natural economy”, an economy based on barter relations which Otto Neurath characterises in the following words:
“The science of the Socialist economy recognises only one single economic master: society itself, which, without reckoning of profit or loss, without the circulation of any form of money, whether it be precious metals or ’labour money’ reflecting an economlc plan, organises production without the.aid of any unit of accounting control and distributes the means of life according to Socialist principles.”
(O. Neurath: “Wirtschaftsplan und.Naturalrechnung” (“Economic Plan and Accounting in Kind), p. 84.)
From 1918 to 1921 the Bolsheviks carried through their attempts to realise this principle in practice, and the last form assumed by these attempts should rightly be seen as the official memorial to its death. In the year 1921 the stabilisation of the rouble was carried through: the return to a “value-based currency” became official policy once again.
The Soviet state was compelled to abandon its perspective of eliminating money from production and distribution, its plan to establish in place of money economic accounting in kind implemented through the agency of the state economy. However, it was in no way “the failure of the world revolution”, not even the alleged unsuitability of individual peasant economy for state economic administration, which had led to this fiasco. All that this experiment had revealed was that production and distribution on this kind of “communist” foundation was impossible. The Russian Revolution had demonstrated in practice that a mode of production without a unit measure of economic regulation and control is no more than an unworkable utopian anomaly!
In the case of the attempt to steer Russian economic life onto a new course, a strictly pre-determined plan was – in the prevailing circumstances quite correctly – resorted to. The separate industrial establishments drew up their production plans and calculated their cost increments, which were then elaborated by the central trust administration into a general plan for the entire trust. The amalgamation of all the plans of all the trusts then gave the All-Russian Congress of Economic Councils a general summary of the entire productive apparatus comprised within the system of state ownership, from which a general plan of production for the whole of state industry could then be drawn up.
But all these plans were based upon a computation in roubles! Why was this not on the basis of a computation in kind?
Because, as far as the fundamental, and hence imperative, categories of the economy are concerned, the mere adding together of the various products of labour – according to weight, physical dimensions or numerical quantity – is a totally pointless exercise. As for the fate suffered by the Russian attempt, described above, it led to the value of the rouble falling very rapidly, and as a consequence the prices of products rose just as fast. As a result, the plans and the cost increments so laboriously calculated only held any validity on paper – for the actual process of production they had no value or meaning whatsoever. Varga, who accepts the merits of the “inflation method” from the point of view of a social strategy, is compelled to admit having found its greatest disadvantage to lie in its ineffectuality as an economic method. He writes:
“The rapid and continuing devaluation of the currency is a disadvantage to the extent that it hinders the stabilisation of wages, calls into being wages struggles, causes disagreements between the state workers and the proletarian state itself, compels the workers continually to demand wage increases, renders all economic calculations extremely difficult and makes impossible both the drawing up of a consistent state budget and, especially, the maintenance of that budget within its set limits.”
(E. Varga: “Die wirtschaftspolitischen Probleme der proletarischen Diktatur” (“Problems of Economic Policy in the Proletarian Dictatorship”), p. 138.)
Thus it is in this way that we can find one of the practical reasons why the Soviet state was compelled to desist from the step of destroying “value-based currency”. Already by 1919 the admission had been made that “accounting according to the value of products is daily becoming more necessary”, so that, already by the time of the Second Economic Congress in l9l9, the decision was taken
“to express all computations of the most important state expenditures according to the values of the products exchanged.”
(A. Goldschmidt: "Die Wirtschaftsorganisation Sowjet-Russlands” (“The Economic Organisation of Soviet Russia”), p. 133.)
It is self-evident that this is only possible if the whole of production stands on the foundation of value. Thus the general stabilisation of the currency had to follow as a necessary consequence.
The Great Bolshevik Experiment in founding a “natural economy” contains two important lessons, the one economic and the other political. These lessons should serve to help the working class develop a proletarian consciousness. The economic lesson is that a rational economy is wholly impossible without a general measure for the accounting of relations in economic life. In order to draw up a production plan it is necessary to know how much labour in its various forms, measured in labour-time (labour-hours) is available and how this labour is to be distributed amongst the various branches of production. Since up till now it has proved impossible to add together tons of steam-coal and hectolitres of corn, it is necessary in the case of all products to leave out of account their form as useful articles, their “use-value”, and to concentrate solely upon that one characteristic which they all without exception possess in common. And that characteristic is that they all embody definite quantities of human labour. The drawing up of a production plan therefore makes it imperative that the quantity of labour required for its production is determined for each single product making up the plan. In a Communist society it is possible to measure this labour directly, without the intermediate distorting-glass of money:
“Society will be able to calculate in a simple way how many hours of labour are contained in a steam-engine, a bushel of the last crop of wheat, or a hundred square yards of cloth of a specific quality. It could therefore never occur to it to go on expressing the quantities of labour put into the products, quantities which it will th en know directly and absolutely, in yet a third product, in a measure which, moreover, is only relative, fluctuating and inadequate, though it was formerly unavoidable as an expedient, rather than express them in their natural, adequate and absolute measure: time.”
(F. Engels: “Anti-Dühring”; Foreign Languages Press, Peking, l976; p. 402.)
As for the political lesson, this consists in the fact that attempts to invest administrative control over the means of production in a central state authority can only lead, in ever increasing degree, to the elimination of the independent initiatives of the workers. Under such a system, it is not possible for the producers to have any control over the product of their labour; the divorce of labour from the product of labour is the essential characteristic of such a mode of production, exactly as under capitalism. Attempts to establish distribution of the product in kind, to proceed to “nationalisation of wages” can, under these conditions, serve only to place control over the sources of the “people’s wealth” ever more firmly in the hands of the central state authority. The growth of “wages in kind”, in its Bolshevik form, is therefore nothing other than the growth of the means for enslaving the working class. In the concentration of power over the objective means of control over the productive apparatus, over social labour and over the total social product in the hands of a central state authority, we perceive the process through which the revolutionary concept of the dictatorship of the proletariat is transformed into its opposite, into the counter-revolutionary concept of a dictatorship over the proletariat.
In the section “The Marxist Definition of the Fundamental Social Preconditions determining the Domination of the Working Class” we have seen that the essential problem confronting Communism lies in overcoming the division between labour and the product of labour. Not some variant of a “Supreme People’s Economic Council”, but the worker-producers themselves must possess the right of control over the product of their labour, and this right must be exercised through their own free and autonomous industrial organisations. Only in this way can they become free producers, and only thus can they have the power to group themselves in a relationship of mutual interdependence,into an Association of Free and Equal Producers. Precisely because contemporary technology has reached a point in its development in which the whole of production is fully socialised, all industrial establishments without exception have been· made completely dependent upon one another in the technical sense, and so formed into one single uninterrupted labour process. In exactly the same way it is now the task of the revolution, for Communism, to forge them into a single economic unity. This,however, is only possible if the entire economic process is unified by an objective economic law of general validity.
This unity or combination is of a completely different kind to that presented by the so-called theories of “socialisation”. These have never looked any more deeply into the matter .than merely to comprehend the matter purely mechanically, as no more than the organisational amalgamation of the various branches of production. They concern themselves exclusively with the question as to which industries are to be combined and how that problem is to be solved in the purely organisational-technical sense. This has nothing whatever to do with the fundamental laws of motion of a new economic system. In such a situation as the one now prevailing, i.e. prior to the carrying through of the revolutionary destruction of the old capitalist system, it is not possible even to consider such questions, for the simple reason that, before that can be done, it is necessary to have a clear conception concerning the mutual relations which must prevail between the various industrial organisations; that is to say, concerning the fundamental social legality which regulates the relationship of the separate industrial organisations to the economic organism as a whole.
The new general economic law under which the entire economic system is unified into a social whole does not, therefore, at least in the early stages, concern itself in any way with the purely organisational integration of the various sectors of the economy. It is concerned only with establishing the general conditions under which the producers, united with one another through their industrial organisations, participate mutually in the general system of the economy. It is in the first place necessary that these conditions be the same for each economic sector. In contradistinction to Lenin, who proceeds from the principle: “The entire people’s economy is organised according to the example of the Post Office, […] that is our first demand” , we say: “Equal economic conditions for all sectors of social production, that is our first demand”. Only then is it possible to take up the question of the form of organisation to be adopted in its technical sense.
“Equal economic conditions” relates in the first place to the introduction of a firm and universally valid unit measure of economic regulation and control according to which all relations in production and distribution are governed and on the basis of which all accounting computations must be carried out. It is no longer possible for this measure to take the form of money, because there is no longer any “second person” interposed between the worker and his product. The worker now no longer stands as an “alien” over and against the product of social labour. It is of course true that the worker himself does not consume the product which he himself has directly produced; but his product does bear within it a quality which all goods socially produced have in common: the average social labour-time required for its production. Viewed from the social point of view, therefore, all goods are qualitatively completely equal. They differ from one another only in the quantity of social labour which has been expended in the production process. In the same way as the unit of measure for individual labour-time is the labour-hour, in the same way must the . unit of measure for the quantity of social labour contained in products be the Average Social Hour of Labour.
Thus it is revealed as a compelling necessity for the proletarian revolution that all industrial organisations have, as their revolutionary obligation,the duty to compute for all products they have produced the exact amounts of average social labour-time expended in their production, and simultaneously to pass their products on to other industrial organisations or to consumers with the appropriate labour-hour quantum stamped upon it. In exchange for this each industrial organisation has the right to draw upon an equal amount of social labour in the form of other products, in order to be able to contribute towards continuing the production process in accordance with the same method. In this way, all participate in the production process under equal economic conditions. So soon as this system of regulating production and distribution has been established, the whole of economic life, which is al ready socially united through the mutual association of the various partial forms of labour, is now also economically, i.e. socially, regulated.
Capitalism attempts to establish this regulation by organisational means, through the continually increasing concentration of its power in industry. What it achieves is, of course, no more than the organisation of competition on an ever higher and more antagonistic level, with increasingly more catastrophic crises as the result. Attempts are made to ameliorate the contradictions associated therewith by political means, according to the rules of "democracy", and with the aim of ensuring the continuation of the capitalist system on a more secure foundation. This, however, only serves in the end to place on a more organised footing the last and most profound of all capitalism’s many contradictions: that between the capital-owning class and the proletariat. Such a social situation can only be overcome when the workers set themselves free; when they conquer the right to assume command over the means of production and begin to participate in the economic process under conditions of economic equality.
The revolution, however, does not consist solely in a transformation of the economic conditions of production; it also establishes new economic conditions in the sphere of distribution, more specifically in that of individual consumption. So soon as the workers hold the power of disposal over the product of labour in their hands, their relationship to this product must then be established and regulated on a new foundation; i .e., in this sphere also the new production relations must find their culminative completion in a new economic relationship anchored in the new social legality. The workers may indeed possess the power of control over the product of their labour, but this power does not bestow rights in the same form as that in which they existed under capitalism, i.e., in an arbitrarily free right of disposal. The right of disposal over the product of labour can only be exercised under social conditions which are identically equal for all. The producers and consumers are indeed free, but only through the instrumentality of their social interdependence and unity. Each industrial establishment is nothing more than a cell in the great economic organism of society. But it is also not less... than this! Each cell has its own qualitatively defined task, its own differentiated role, which it can fulfil only through its own independent self-activity. And yet, at the same time, this self-activity is only possible in and through the clearly defined framework formed by the general laws of motion of the Communist social organism as a whole. Within this defined framework free autonomous activity and self-movement can develop and unfold, and for this reason the workers become, through the very instrumentality of this framework, free producers.
The equal conditions governing individual consumption can, on the other hand, be made manifest only through the same unit of measurement as that which is applied to consumption as a whole. In the same way as the individual hour of labour is the unit of measurement for the labour contributed by the individual, so also is the individual hour of labour at the same time the measurement for individual consumption. By this means consumption also is socially regulated and moves within limits which are fully and clearly defined.
In its essence, therefore, the social revolution is nothing more than the introduction of the labour-hour as the unit measure regulating and controlling of the whole of economic life. It serves as the measure in production, and simultaneously the right of the producers to their share in the social product is measured through its instrumentality. The most essential characteristic in all this, however; is that this unit measure, as the universal category of economic regulation and control, is implemented and carried through by the producers and consumers themselves. And this is so, not because it is an “ethical” or “moral” demand of Communism, but because, from the point of view of economic reality, nothing else is possible. It is, of course, also true that the elimination of unequal rights in the exploitation of labour, the precondition for the full unfolding and development of the free human being, is also an ethical demand. But this only proves yet again that the spheres of economy and social ethics can only realise themselves through their mutual interdependence – they both become fused together into a single unity.
1. In German: “Hie Sozialdemokratie – Hie Staatssozialismus”, translated twice wrongly with “forward to”.
© Allthough the Communist Left in general abstained from claiming copyrights or rights on “intellectuel property”, some publications on this site might be copyrighted; if they are, their use is free for personal consultation only. Non-copyrighted material, provided for non-commercial use only, can be freely distributed. Including a reference to this source is appreciated, as well as a notification. As for commercial use, please contact us.
Compiled by Vico, 7 May 2016